The good fight
As campaigns heat up
throughout New England, it looks like cities will lead the way in the battle
for a living wage
by Noah Bruce
Living wage laws are designed to help the working people at the bottom of the
economic ladder. The premise behind the movement is that no one who is working
should live in poverty. That seems pretty reasonable.
Yet, according to UMass-Amherst professor of Labor Studies Stephanie Luce, at
least 25 percent of the American workforce -- roughly 32.5 million workers --
earn less than the federal poverty line for a family of four -- $17,650. The
majority of the working poor are women -- 31 percent of working women earn less
than $8 an hour, compared with only 20 percent of men.
Part of the problem is the minimum wage. At the current $5.15 an hour,
assuming an eight-hour day, a 40-hour week, and a 50-week year, minimum wage
pays $206 a week: $10,300 a year. Less than that when Social Security is
subtracted. While this may be enough if you're a high-schooler living with your
parents, you don't have to be an economist to realize that in today's world you
can't live on ten grand a year, and you certainly can't raise a family on this
kind of money.
Of course, it's never been easy to live on the minimum wage, but over the past
three decades it has become decidedly more difficult. Simply put, the minimum
wage, which requires an act of Congress to raise, has not kept pace with
inflation.
In 2000 dollars, a minimum wage job in 1969 paid $6.99 an hour. By 1979, the
figure was down almost a quarter to $6.75. Ten years later, it bottomed out at
a measly $4.65. Through two raises in the '90s, the minimum wage has begun to
poke its head out of the hole, but the fact is that America's working poor have
not benefited from the economic boom of the past 20 years.
Organizers have decided the most practical route to lifting up the working
poor is through changes made to the use of public money. Therefore, living wage
ordinances harness the power of government as an employer, a purchaser of
services, and a subsidizer of private enterprise to pay workers a decent
wage.
THOUGH THE term "living wage ordinance" is used differently by different
activists, for the sake of this discussion it is defined as a law at either the
city, state, or county level that mandates an hourly rate above the federal or
state minimum wage for included workers. Included workers can work for
employers from three categories -- government, companies with government
contracts, and companies that receive government subsidies.
Cambridge is the only New England city with an ordinance that affects all
three categories. Boston, New Haven, Connecticut, and Hartford have laws
affecting city contractors, while Somerville, Massachusetts, passed an
ordinance including city employees and those who work for contractors.
Burlington, Montpelier, and Barre, Vermont have laws ensuring that government
employees receive a living wage.
City councils in both Providence and Bridgeport, Connecticut, are currently
considering instituting comprehensive ordinances like one in Cambridge.
If instituted, the Providence ordinance will mandate a living wage of $12.30,
the highest in the country. Bridgeport is not far behind with $11.08. Like many
living wages, both figures are based on the federal poverty line. In the case
of Providence, it's 150 percent of the wages necessary to keep a family of four
at the line, 130 percent for Bridgeport.
One significant difference is in the treatment of benefits, or rather lack of
benefits. Under the Providence law, if an employer fails to provide health
benefits, they must tack on an additional $4.02, bringing the total living wage
sans health benefits to $16.32. Not a bad wage to drive a bus or sweep floors.
In Bridgeport employers must pay an additional $1.50 per hour.
The laws are similar in the employers they cover. They include the cities of
Providence and Bridgeport as employers; any company in Providence that holds a
contract or subcontract with the city worth $25,000, in Bridgeport the contract
must be worth $50,000; and any company that receives a subsidy, loan, or bond
from either city worth $100,000.
The Providence and Bridgeport campaigns demonstrate how newer campaigns are
building upon foundations laid by earlier laws. According to Jon Green, head
organizer at ACORN Connecticut, the lead organization in the Bridgeport
campaign, his job is made easier by the previous efforts in Hartford and New
Haven. "It is definitely helpful that other cities in the state have done
this," he says. "We're not breaking the mold. It makes people feel more
comfortable."
In addition to the comfort factor of exploring charted territory, the
Bridgeport and Providence campaigns both borrow language directly from laws in
Boston and Hartford.
Both campaigns borrow a provision in the Boston law that requires included
companies to post jobs with "community-based hiring halls" and consider hiring
folks referred by the halls before looking elsewhere to fill a position. The
halls will be operated by community non-profits and unions and, according to
Mathew Jerzyk of RI Jobs with Justice, will ensure that "folks in the community
have access to the jobs first." Green adds that this provision enables the
"transforming of neighborhoods" as many of the halls will be located with
organizations that work with poorer communities. "If you get 50 new jobs in the
east side [of Bridgeport] that could mean 50 more people with mortgages . . .
That could mean a new business could open up in the neighborhood or a business
that doesn't have to close its doors."
Borrowing from the Hartford ordinance, Providence and Bridgeport include a
provision that ensures that affected employers will not impede the forming of a
union. In exchange, the new union promises not to strike for the duration of
the contract. "The idea is to make it easier to organize unions," says Green
and to help ensure "labor peace" which is "in the best interest of the city."
While there has not yet been much opposition to the law in Bridgeport, the
same cannot be said for Providence. where the business community has come out
as "definitely opposed to it, absolutely," in the words of Jim Hagan, president
of the Greater Providence Chamber of Commerce. "We think it would make the city
uncompetitive." Hagan's principal argument is simple and is at the heart of the
opposition to living wage laws all over the country. He believes forcing
affected employers to pay higher wages will dissuade companies from moving to
Providence and will force businesses -- especially small businesses -- already
in Providence to leave. Thus, he reasons, Providence will suffer economically,
employment will go down, and the ordinance will end up hurting the low-wage
workers it was designed to help.
Hagan is not alone. University of Notre Dame professor of economics Thomas
Gresik says that, for an employer, the hiring process is a gamble, and "an
artificially inflated wage," he believes, increases the stakes of this gamble,
making employers less willing to hire. "If you have to pay those wages," he
says, "you're not going to be willing to hire those workers."
He further argues that after a living wage ordinance is passed, "the people
lining up for the [new higher paid] work," are, for the most part workers "with
bad reputations or no experience." In other words, crummy, or at the very
least, unproven. The logic runs that the superior employees will have already
found better work and do not need the help afforded under a living wage law.
To support his argument, Gresik presents the hypothetical situation wherein,
instead of raising the wage, a city lowers it. "Suppose you were to lower the
wage. Folks that were conscientious, they're going to have opportunities. It's
the folks with bad reputations and no experience that are going to be left
behind." If we flip things over to the proposed situation where the wage is
raised, it's these same irreputable louts, in Gresik's view, who benefit.
Gresik's argument rests on the tenet of pure capitalism that the marketplace
rewards good, conscientious workers and punishes the slack and lazy.
Yet, does anyone really believe that the 25 to 30 percent of Americans who
work jobs that pay under $17,650 (the poverty line for a family of four) are
all slothful or incompetent?
If not, then one must conclude that the marketplace does not necessarily
reward good workers. As Richard McIntyre, professor of economics at the
University of Rhode Island, writes in his report, The Providence Jobs and
Living Wage Ordinance, "Minimum- and living wage laws raise the uncomfortable
truth that some workers do not receive the true value of their contribution in
`free' labor markets." In fact, oftentimes the market screws those at the
bottom to save money.
Such was the case with Sara Gonzalez, a teacher's assistant in the Providence
school system who for three years worked for $5.65 an hour without benefits. If
she worked 60 days straight the school was required to pay her a better rate
and provide benefits. To get around this stipulation, every 59 days the
administration at her school would "terminate" her to keep her from receiving
benefits and full-time pay only to re-hire her and start her at day one.
Gonzalez, who is a mother of three, was clearly not lazy -- during the
three-year stretch she worked a second job at a grocery store. And she doesn't
lack gumption -- finally after three years she and her co-workers organized and
had meetings with the School Department, resulting in full-time employment.
Today, Gonzalez is one of the organizers working on Providence's living wage
ordinance.
IN AN effort to bring jobs to their area, state and local governments have been
doling out tax breaks to attract companies since the 1930s. However, according
to Greg Leroy, director of Good Jobs First, a project sponsored by the
Institute for Taxation and Economic Policy, corporate welfare didn't begin in
earnest until the recession in the early 1980s.
At the time, Saturn was deciding where to locate its new factory, and a
virtual frenzy of incentive one-upmanship erupted between states trying to
attract Saturn. The effort culminated in eight governors taking the rather
embarrassing step of appearing on The Phil Donahue Show to beg Saturn to
come to their state. Finally, Tennessee won with a deal including tax breaks
worth $50,000 per new job. A decade later, in 1993, the stakes had grown to the
point where Alabama gave Mercedes Benz $168,000 per job to locate a new factory
in the Cotton state.
Today, subsidizing corporate investment is standard operating procedure for
state and especially local governments. Large companies frequently lure cities
into bidding wars with other cities in an attempt to bring the sought-after
jobs to their market. "In America, if you are a company," says Leroy, "and
you've made a large-scale investment, and your CFO is awake, you've gotten
subsidies . . . They are so easy to get."
While the Saturn and Mercedes figures may seem outlandish, at least the
manufacturing jobs they brought were well paid. Far worse is the case when a
city or state bends over for a company that thanks the city by offering a bunch
of minimum-wage jobs, and this seems too often be the case.
"Many cities still operate on the premise that any job is a good job, not
thinking about long-term economic development," says Jen Kern director of the
Association of Community Organizations for Reform Now's (ACORN), Living Wage
Resource Center, a group that tracks living wage campaigns across the country.
"Cities that are most desperate think they have to do this," she says. "If a
city spends its limited resources on enriching a company that has no commitment
to paying good wages, you are going to have a city that, due to poverty, will
be the least attractive to businesses."
This approach hurts not only the folks who end up with the low-paying jobs, as
Pingree pointed out, but taxpayers in general, who end up subsidizing the
low-wage workers who, more often than not, receive benefits from the government
like food stamps and Medicaid. "As a taxpayer, I have a self interest in
subsidizing companies that pay a good wage," says Leroy.
TO PREDICT how Providence's law would impact its business community, we can
look to examples provided by the 60-plus cities with living wage ordinances.
Gresik points out that there is little hard data from these examples, and Luce,
the UMass professor who co-authored a book on the subject, entitled The
Living Wage: Building a Fair Economy (New Press, 2000), admits "there is
less data than one would expect," primarily because most of the laws are very
recent.
However, data does exist. According to an evaluation conducted by the Economic
Policy Institute (EPI), a Washington-based think tank, "Baltimore's living wage
ordinance found no job loss as a result of the ordinance." Further it states
"the majority of workers interviewed for the study reported no changes in the
number of hours they worked after the ordinance went into effect." Some
contractors in this report said the ordinance leveled the playing field by
eliminating pressure to cut labor costs in order to win city contracts.
A report on the San Jose ordinance conducted by the San Jose Office of Quality
Assurance found no evidence that contractors were unwilling to make bids with
the city as a result of the ordinance. According to Luce, an impact study done
in Los Angeles that studied 30 government contractors reported that only five
claimed to have reduced employment minimally.
One of the arguments in favor of the living-wage ordinance is that at least
some of the money municipalities and businesses lose by paying higher wages is
made up by decreased turnover, training, and hiring costs, and increased
productivity. Still it is unrealistic to believe that large numbers of low-wage
workers will receive pay raises without someone else losing money.
As McIntyre writes in his report on the Providence ordinance, "Scenarios where
everyone wins are always attractive but they are rare in practice. It is likely
that some of the income gains achieved by low-income workers through this
ordinance will come at the expense of contractor profits. It is likely the
amount will be low, but the transfer aspects should be honestly
acknowledged."
Luce's research supports McIntyre's prediction that businesses will lose
profits, but only slightly. "Our research shows," she says, that the ordinances
"cost on average one percent of a firm's total cost of doing business."
However, this is before factoring reduced training costs and increased
productivity into the equation.
Evidence suggests costs to governments are similarly low. A study published by
the Center for Labor Research and Studies at the Florida International
University before Dade County, Florida, enacted a living wage law in 1999
estimated costs at .01 to .02 percent of the county's operating budget.
It is clear that living wage ordinances are no panacea -- EPI reports that
local governments are often slow to enact the procedures necessary to monitor
companies' compliance and the laws leave many workers unaffected (according to
McIntyre, if the Providence law were enacted in 1999 it would effect 313
workers). McIntyre argues that even the Providence law, which would provide the
highest living wage in the country, "does not truly provide a `living' wage, if
by that we mean what is necessary to support a family of three at a modest
standard without income supports or child and medical care subsidies."
On the other hand, even Luce, who is a proponent of the ordinances, agrees
with Gresik on the premise that at some level a living wage will negatively and
significantly affect employment. The question is where is that level and is the
proposed $12.30 ($16.02 without bennies) above it?
Unfortunately, neither Luce, nor other economists, seem to have an answer.
NATIONALLY, the living wage movement is growing. According to ACORN's Living
Wage Resource, since 1994, when Baltimore passed the first living wage law in
the country, over 60 cities have followed suit and passed ordinances of their
own. The center lists current campaigns in over 75 cities spread across the
country, including the New England cities of Brookline, Massachusetts, and New
Britain, Connecticut, and Portsmouth, New Hampshire.
This is a true grass-roots movement working toward loosening the bonds of
poverty on at least some of America's working poor. On its site, ACORN quotes
syndicated columnist Robert Kuttner calling the movement "the most interesting
(and underreported) grassroots enterprise to emerge since the civil rights
movement . . . signaling a resurgence of local activism around pocketbook
issues."
In a startling move that could broaden the scope of the living wage movement,
in May, Santa Monica, California passed an ordinance that guaranteed $10.50
plus benefits to all workers in the city's tourism district. This is big news
because it applies to all workers, not just those that work for the city, a
city contractor, or a city-subsidized company.
According to an article by Vivian Rothstein that appeared on Alternet.org on
May 29, the law is still indirectly based on the argument that businesses that
benefit from taxpayer money should pay a living wage. A decade ago, Santa
Monica invested $170 million in taxpayer money to revitalize its tourist
district. The measure paid off, and turned "Santa Monica into one of the
nation's most lucrative seaside resort towns," says Rothstein. However, the
hotels that benefited from the tourism boom still paid thousands of service
workers poverty wages.
This new law opens up the realm of the living wage ordinance. If
municipalities can target entire sectors of their economies that have benefited
from public money but still pay low wages, the number of workers affected by
living wage laws would increase dramatically. Rothstein says, "The most likely
candidates for future campaigns are tourism-oriented cities where a substantial
investment of taxpayer dollars has generated a booming economy supported by
low-wage workers." Kind of sounds like Portland.
However, if laws like Santa Monica's spread, expect a strong backlash from the
business community. Already, in Santa Monica, the hotels are threatening legal
action.
Another significant offshoot of the movement is its spread to college
campuses. In what may be at least a small resurgence of campus activism,
according to ACORN, students at over 10 colleges are demanding that workers at
their schools receive a living wage. On May 9, 26 student protesters at Harvard
ended a three-week sit-in of an administration building after the university
promised to re-examine university wage policies for low-paid workers and
contractors. Also in May, students at UConn took over an administration
building and won a living wage for janitors subcontracted by the university.
"The living wage movement is a very significant development moving toward
economic justice in our time," says Paul Sherry, a social activist who now
consults with living-wage campaign organizers in Cleveland. "In an effective
way, it relates the morality of working towards the goal of people having
sufficient resources to live with an effective method for change. It combines
good ethics with sound practical politics."
Sherry believes there is a "renewed commitment to economic justice in the
religious community" reflected in the participation of churches with
progressive activists and organized labor in most living wage campaigns.
The collaboration of leadership from these activist communities have led the
campaigns in cities throughout New England, a region that has played host to a
hotbed of living wage organizing. The laws are especially significant here
because, according to Jared Bernstein, an economist with the Economic Policy
Institute, we have the highest cost of living in the United States.
While it has worked to see that subsidized companies pay decent wages, unlike
campaigns in Massachusetts and Connecticut and to some extent Vermont, the
Maine effort has not looked at the issue of paying city employees or, more
importantly, city contractors a living wage.
THE FAILED BILL in Maine focused on the role of government as a subsidizer and
with good reason -- Maine is a state that doles out a lot of corporate welfare.
For fiscal year 2002, the Maine budget allocates $60 million for its largest
subsidy, the BETR program. In 2003, the figure will climb to $68 million says
Christopher St. John, executive director of the non-profit Maine Center for
Economic Policy, and it is growing quicker than planned. "In its seventh year,
the BETR program will reach where it was supposed to be in its twelfth year,"
he says.
Passing a statewide living wage bill may not be politically feasible at this
time. That doesn't mean the living wage campaign in Maine is dead, but in the
future it will most likely manifest at the municipal level like it did in
Lewiston-Auburn in 1999.
In that year, the sister cities jointly passed a law requiring that companies
that receive tax increment financing (known as a TIF) must pay a "livable wage"
of $9.32 an hour. According to Lincoln Jeffers, an economic development
specialist with the city of Lewiston, the law has not been an impediment to
attracting companies to the city at all. "We have not seen any of that," he
says. However, as the empty storefronts will attest, Lewiston/Auburn isn't
exactly a boom-town.
Still there may be new municipal campaigns brewing in the state. The efforts
at the state level in Maine and in Lewiston-Auburn reflect what Greg Leroy,
director of Good Jobs First, calls "an absolute trend to attaching wage and
health care requirements to subsidies." Leroy says this trend reveals that
municipalities are waking up to the fact that they can use subsidies
selectively to spur positive economic development.
"The whole purpose of development is to develop the economy," says Leroy. "I
think that means to raise the living standards of the common people."
Noah Bruce can be reached at nbruce[a]phx.com.